Citation: Hiedanpää J, Borgström S (2014) Why do some institutional arrangements succeed? Voluntary protection of forest biodiversity in Southwestern Finland and of the Golden Eagle in Finnish Lapland. Nature Conservation 7: 29–50. doi: 10.3897/natureconservation.7.6497
Despite global, regional, and national policy efforts, biodiversity is on the decline worldwide. The purpose of this paper is to explore the critically important institutional and social features of those economic instruments that in practice motivate beneficiaries and stakeholders to protect biodiversity. The paper presents two case studies: the natural values trading (NVT) scheme in southwestern Finland and the protection of the golden eagle (Aquila chrysaetos) in Finnish Lapland. NVT builds upon the voluntary actions of landowners, payments for ecosystem services, and a fixed-term period of protection (ten years). The protection of the golden eagle is based on tolerance payments. This paper combines legal studies and institutional economics to abduct the reasons underlying the success of both cases. In both cases, institutional entrepreneurship promoted the confidence of stakeholders and beneficiaries in the schemes and the consequent trust amongst the agents encouraged the actors to modify their behaviour.
Environmental law, Institutional economics, Biodiversity conservation, Economic instruments: Payments for ecosystem services, Pragmatism
In recent years, economic instruments for biodiversity protection have regained their lustre as the concept of ecosystem services has gained attention amongst governments, civil societies, and the media. Ecosystem services have rapidly become the mainstream means by which to describe the benefits of nature (ecosystems, biodiversity) to society. This concept is now used for many purposes (
In most payment schemes, a government pays for ecosystem services (
The launch of the Natura 2000 nature conservation programme in 1997 attracted unprecedented attention in northern Satakunta. As a culmination, four local forest owners went on a hunger strike to protest how the reserve network had been planned, saying that their opinions had not been considered and that social and cultural considerations and values had been completely side-lined in the planning process. Their campaign attracted nationwide attention, including personal visits by the Minister of the Environment and the Minister for Agriculture and Forestry. As a consequence, the boundaries of some of the sites were redrawn (
The idea of NVT was first floated in the mid-1990s by Raimo Hakila. First principles of it were drafted during the development phase in 2001–2002. The phase gave credence to the idea that NVT was indeed a viable approach to tackling the problem of forest biodiversity, even at the national level (
In essence, NVT, as it was tested as part of the METSO programme in 2003–2007, provides forest owners in certain ecologically valuable areas with a voluntary choice between producing natural values or timber. There were two buyers in NVT: the Regional Forest Centre and the Regional Environment Centre. The eligible sellers included all those forest owners (in total 45 000) in southwestern Finland who had sites and habitats in their forests that meet the specified criteria. Local municipalities and businesses are not parties to NVT because they are not eligible for benefits under the Act on the Financing of Sustainable Forestry. The contracts have terms of ten years; they are not agreements in perpetuity.
It was preferable that the contract sites fulfilled the Biological Nature Conservation Criteria (BNCC). The criteria are based on the forests structures and dynamics important for biodiversity and valuable forest habitats. Forest structures include, e.g. coarse woody debris, burned wood, old individual stands of hardwood and other deciduous trees, especially aspen. The criteria for certain forest habitat types include firstly primary criteria for identifying the forest habitat and its representativeness, secondly criteria for landscape ecological location and area, and thirdly complementary criteria for additional biodiversity values. Forest habitats include forests in a natural or semi-natural stage, forested mires, hardwood swamps, herb-rich forests, rich heath forests, and semi-natural grazed forests. (
During the experimental phase, from 2003 to 2007, 158 contracts were signed. The contract area covered 1, 520 hectares, 1, 193 hectares of which fulfilled the BNCC. The average size of the area covered by the contracts was 8.8 hectares. The average payment was €155 per hectare per year, whereas on the sites that did not fulfil the biological criteria, the average payment was €31 per hectare per year. In total, 356 land owners committed forestland to NVT. There were more sites offered than accepted and more sites than contracts, although some contracts covered more than one site. However, every contract covered sites that fulfilled the biological criteria. Most of the contracts were agreed upon because there was decaying wood on the site; that is, old, dry, peaty forest. Managerial conservation actions were included in 35 of the contracts (
The golden eagle has been protected in Finland since 1962, when the population had declined to between 20 and 50 pairs. Since then, conservation efforts have led to a substantial recovery of the species. In 1999, there were 175 known nesting territories. However, the recovery of the species has led to a conflict between species conservation and reindeer husbandry (
Because the golden eagle preys on reindeer calves, the conservation of this species has been in conflict with reindeer herding in Finnish Lapland (
The Ministry of the Environment then began to develop the scheme, and the core idea of the Swedish model was taken as a point of departure. The preparation of the golden eagle compensation scheme continued as collaboration between the Ministry of the Environment and the Forest and Parks Services. The proposed design was then discussed with the representatives of the Sami people, the Association of the Reindeer Co-operatives, the Regional Environmental Centre of Lapland, and a representative of the individual reindeer owners. Consultations led to amendments to the proposal and the final scheme. For example, the golden eagles nesting in neighbouring countries were taken into account. It was clear from the beginning that to gain acceptability, the design and implementation of the golden eagle compensation scheme would require strong co-operation among the stakeholders.
The golden eagle compensation scheme was implemented in 1999 (Council of State Decision 373/1999, later replaced by Council of State Decree on Compensation of the Losses Caused to Reindeer Husbandry by the Golden Eagle 8/2002). In conjunction with the adoption of the scheme, a negotiating group was set up. The group consists of the representatives of the Forests and Parks Services, the Regional Environmental Centre of Lapland, the Association of the Reindeer Co-operatives, the Sami Parliament, the Finnish Game and Fisheries Research Institute, and the Ministry of the Environment (
The incentive scheme is based on information about the golden eagle’s known nesting territories (
The financial payment is made to individual reindeer co-operatives (Government decree 8/2002 6 §). If it can be proven that a golden eagle has killed a reindeer belonging to an individual reindeer owner, the co-operative must compensate the owner for the value of the reindeer (Government decree 8/2002 7 §). Otherwise, the co-operative decides how to use the annual payments. For example, the funds can be divided among the reindeer owners who have suffered losses, or the funds can be used for collectively beneficial projects, such as product development or meat production facilities (
Our empirical task is to analyse the social preconditions and institutional conditions underlying the motivational success of these cases. We define success not only by positive ecological outcomes but also by positive social, cultural and political outcomes. These instruments have been viewed as acceptable and legitimate amongst those affected and, consequently, have had positive effects on how biodiversity and its protection have been perceived (
Nevertheless, both schemes are intended to provide incentives for biodiversity protection rather than merely relying on traditional direct regulation that prohibits certain types of activities and punishes violations. However, we argue that also other features have contributed to the success of these governance experiments leading to wider effects on biodiversity governance in Finland. Identifying some of the critical similarities and differences between these two cases should enable us to reach conclusions concerning the critical conditions for the institutional and regulatory design of nature conservation that motivates beneficiaries and stakeholders to participate and act.
The approach taken in this study is a combination of institutional economics (
In institutional economics, pragmatism implies that “[i]ndividual habits both reinforce, and are reinforced by, institutions. Through this circle of mutual engagement, institutions are endowed with a stable and inert quality. Further, institutions play an essential role in providing a cognitive framework for interpreting sense-data and in providing intellectual habits or routines for transforming information into useful knowledge” (
In legal studies, pragmatism implies that the approach to law is instrumental. Law is seen as an instrument used to achieve societal objectives by creating new formal conditions to change habits that are considered problematic (
Our research materials consist of legal and policy documents and scientific literature concerning both cases. In addition, we have applied qualitative research methods, namely, theme interviews and participant observation. The first author participated as an observer at the meetings of the NVT steering group (
The following result section is a thick description (
NVT
The collaborative steering group soon recognised that for natural values to become tradable goods, they had to be identified and itemised apart from their environment. The identification and definition of natural values for the purposes of NVT is based on the biological nature conservation criteria (BNCC) specified in the METSO program (
In NVT, a natural value is owned by the person who owns the land that features a valuable structural or functional characteristic. From the landowner’s point of view, NVT refers to a fixed-term contract concerning a certain land area, such as a patch of old-growth forest. In this way, the natural value becomes a transferable private commodity that the landowner can either sell or withhold from selling. Therefore, the state-as-buyer is primarily interested not in the land itself but rather in the ecosystem services produced by that biologically valuable patch of land. In other words, the natural value of the land is an intangible public commodity that the state wants to conserve.
The BBNC were adopted in the NVT scheme. However, these criteria have not been rigorously applied in every transaction, although the collaborative steering group has allowed for local exceptions, and the ministries have not objected. In this way, landowners have effectively been involved in defining the criteria upon which ecological characteristics have been defined as tradable commodities and the prices paid for them. In cases in which the conservation criteria have not been met but NVT contracts have been signed, the areas concerned have either been close to a nature conservation area or have been part of some other valuable habitat or the contract has involved management or restoration measures aimed at increasing biodiversity at the site.
The collaborative steering group decided that the prices of natural values would be determined based on losses sustained from forgoing timber production. In addition, payment was done for the natural value of the site and any forest management measures undertaken. Once the pilot project was underway, the emphasis shifted rapidly from the compensation of losses from forgoing timber production to natural values. The prices of these values were based on the surface areas of valuable habitats, standing trees, and the structural ecological characteristics of natural values. The latter included exposed decaying wood, burned wood, and broad-leafed deciduous species, especially aspen. Management measures are compensated for according to the Act on the Financing of Sustainable Forestry. The government has also contributed by declaring income from NVT to be tax exempt.
Instead of a fixed price table, the collaborative steering group created a five-tiered pricing framework for forest structures to help determine the economic value of each NVT site. The forest owner’s tendering price could be higher or lower than that indicated by the pricing framework. If the asking price was higher, the forest owner was asked to give reasons for her or his price. No reason was needed if the price was lower, but the forest owner needed to be informed that he or she could have received a higher price. The referendary had a 15 per cent bargaining leeway in either direction. The price paid for natural values could not exceed the top level, but it could be lower than the lower limit.
Golden eagle
In Finnish legal culture, wild animals have been regarded as res nullius, nobody’s property (
It is rational for the state to cover such damages; otherwise, those who suffer harm from wild animals would have an incentive to harass or kill the species that cause damage. The way in which the state compensates for the damage is relevant. By choosing the compensation measure, the legislature can regulate behaviour, habits, and perceptions regarding biodiversity protection. In the case of the golden eagle, the legislature created an incentive for conservation by paying for the natural values instead of for the damage caused by the species.
Previously, the presence of the golden eagle only created an economic burden for reindeer owners; now, they have an opportunity to gain economic benefit from the presence of the bird. This argument was used to convince the reindeer owners to commit to the scheme (
NVT
Raimo Hakila took an active role in exploring new alternative approaches to protect and produce natural values. During the experimental phase, he was on the payroll of the Satakunta branch of the Central Union of Agricultural Producers and Forest Owners (MTK) (
Science also played a role in changing old habits. As soon as NVT was initiated, the collaborative steering group decided to convene an informal multidisciplinary group of researchers who would potentially be interested in studying the social and ecological conditions for NVT. The circle of researchers from several universities and research institutes held its first meeting in Pori on 13 June 2003, just one week after the first official collaborative steering group meeting. A large number of researchers were interested in this voluntary arrangement for biodiversity conservation. This habit of convening in Pori once a year continued throughout the pilot.
The motivation for encouraging multidisciplinary research stemmed from the desire to gain a clearer picture of how NVT works in practice and what impact it has. The collaborative steering group primarily worked to achieve institutional goals, i.e., to create and establish the rules and practices of trading. However, the group has had confidence in the positive economic and ecological impacts of NVT. Most of the researchers who accepted the initial challenge to study NVT were social scientists, particularly economists. The composition of the circle is different from that in the Biodiversity Research Programme MOSSE (2002–2006), for instance, in which natural scientists are in the majority. The results were encouraging for the NVT pilot project (
Golden eagle
As noted above, the golden eagle compensation scheme was subsequently revised as the responsibility for compensation was transferred to the Ministry of Environment. Therefore, it was easy to build a new scheme at the administrative level because there were no old organisational habits or structures to be changed.
The greatest organisational change was the increased collaboration among the authorities (the Ministry of the Environment, the Forest and Parks Services, and the Regional Environment Centre in Lapland), volunteer bird watchers, and reindeer owners. This collaboration was formalised with the establishment of the working group in conjunction with the adoption of the scheme. The group follows on-going research on the golden eagle and its effects on reindeer husbandry (
The systematic search for golden eagle nests started as early as 1958, and the Forest and Parks Services have been responsible for the identification and management of golden eagle nests since 1983. Given that the golden eagle compensation scheme adopted in 1999 is based on information about known nesting territories, there was a need for more research and information sharing between the reindeer owners and researchers to ensure the accuracy of the payments. The territories are monitored twice annually: decorated nests (occupied territories) are counted in May, and the offspring are counted in occupied territories in June. Each year, the Forest and Parks Services inform the representatives of each reindeer co-operative about known nests. In turn, the reindeer owners inform the Services representative about potential or suspected nests, which are then monitored by the Forest and Parks Services (
NVT
In NVT, forest owners now had two alternatives: they were compensated for refraining from doing anything or for making an active choice to do something. In the passive approach to natural values production, forest owners simply allow natural values to exist. In the active approach, they may increase the amount of exposed decaying wood, remove species that do not belong to the habit in question, or perform other management or restorative activities to preserve or strengthen natural values. Approximately 40 of the 115 NVT contracts involve active measures by forest owners. Compensation for forest management measures is paid in accordance with the Act on the Financing of Sustainable Forestry.
Hakila and other members of the collaborative steering group were been unanimous in their view of landowners: with respect to the protection of biodiversity, landowners are motivated not by a sense of moral obligation but by the possibility of financial profit. Hakila in particular stressed that individual motives for action are not important in instrument design; what matters is that agreements are reached, that the principles of NVT are more widely adopted, that people learn what the programme is about, and that trading achieves a more established position in the protection of biodiversity. According to Hakila, the sense of moral obligation will follow later of its own accord.
One of the ways in which forest owners’ sense of profit were bolstered was by helping them identify natural values in their own forests and determine the price of these values. The collaborative steering group repeatedly emphasised the need to strengthen landowners’ commitment to voluntary conservation. Traditionally, nature conservation areas have been kept strictly separate from land designated for forestry use. Hakila, in particular, argued for the need to combine these two categories into a concept of a commercially managed forest in which forestry is practised in such a way that no danger is caused to the typical or unique natural values of the area or, indeed, where those values are reinforced by the practice of forestry. By giving up a small slice of the traditional value added by forestry, it is possible to protect biodiversity and increase economic activity at both the individual and regional levels.
Hakila also attempted to integrate economic history and local activity as part of the protection of biodiversity and sustainable use. Virtually all areas that are significant from a biodiversity perspective, have been objects of human activity and that the safeguarding of biodiversity in these areas requires the continuation of that activity. This was a positive message for farmers in two ways: first, they were no longer accused of impoverishing biodiversity, and second, their active contribution was needed to help resolve the biodiversity problem.
Golden eagle
What makes the golden eagle case especially interesting is that reindeer husbandry is a traditional source of income for the Sami people. The Sami, who are the only indigenous people in the European Union, are a minority whose language and culture are protected by provisions such as Article 27 of the International Covenant on Civil and Political Rights. This article allows special treatment (positive discrimination) for the Sami to protect their culture and may also be used as a material basis for the protection of their culture. Both forms of protection are safeguarded by the fundamental rights set out in the Finnish Constitution. In addition to the conflict that the recovery of the golden eagle has caused between the conservation of the species and reindeer herding, other environmental conflicts related to the traditional livelihoods of the Sami have arisen. For example, the conflict between state forestry and Sami reindeer herding led to appeals to the UN Human Rights Committee (UNHRC) (
According to a survey conducted in 2005, the reindeer owners’ attitudes towards nature can mostly be described as utilitarian. Most reindeer owners accept the presence of carnivores in reindeer herding areas, but only if the damages are fully compensated; they also feel that humans have the right to regulate the population of wild animals as they wish (
Nevertheless, the scheme did not gain full acceptance immediately. The Supreme Administrative Court in Finland had to review the incentive scheme, as one of the co-operatives made an appeal against the compensation decision in 1999 because the compensation did not cover the confirmed losses of the co-operative. The co-operative consisted mainly of Sami people and argued that the scheme was contrary to Article 27 of the United Nations International Covenant on Civil and Political Rights (1966). That covenant states that in States containing ethnic minorities, for example, persons belonging to such minorities shall not be denied the right, in community with the other members of their group, to enjoy their own culture. The Supreme Administrative Court found in its decision (KHO 12.9.2002 file 2154) that the incentive scheme did not deny the right of the Sami people to enjoy their culture.
Over the years, however, the reindeer owners have learned to trust in the accuracy of the compensation, and the scheme has gained acceptance (Sippola et al. 2005). The role of the research and the trust towards the researchers have been important in this regard. As reindeer owners have become convinced that the compensation rate would increase as new occupied territories were found, but not vice versa (that is, there is no collective punishment for destroyed nests, as the compensations already paid are not required to be paid back), the trust felt by reindeer owners towards the scheme and authorities has increased (
The incentive-based scheme has enabled a shift in reindeer owners’ behaviour. Instead of using time and money to find reindeer carcasses and verify damage, they are now able to act for golden eagle conservation because they have incentives to both inform the authorities of nests found and protect their reindeer from damage.
NVT
NVT became standardised with the renewed law on “Financing Sustainable Forestry” (Law on the Financing of Sustainable Forestry 544/2007) in 2008. However, the original parameters have not survived unscathed. The authoritative agents changed some features as the policy innovation was formalised. First, natural values (ecosystem services) are not actually paid for; only the values of timber losses are compensated, according to the list price of €39 per hectare per year. This modification was required because the EU forbids the Finnish government to support forestry in a way that might distort competition with regard to forest-related goods (European Commission C (2008)460/2, Brussels, 13 II 2008.) Second, all accepted sites must fulfil the Biological Nature Conservation Criteria (BNCC) (
The NVT scheme needed to be revised because the EU Commission required the scheme to be consistent with the state aid regulations of the Treaty on the Functioning of the European Union. According to the commission, the forest owners can only be compensated for loss of income (European Commission C (2008)460/2, Brussels, 13 II 2008). Thus, the state cannot offer any compensation that is greater than the loss of income resulting from forgoing timber production, even for sites that would be highly valuable for nature conservation purposes.
In the initial scheme, the price varied according to the ecological significance of the natural values being protected, timber losses, and completed management work, and site selection was contingently stretched outside the criteria of the BNCC. This approach enabled forest owners to suggest the inclusion of areas of lesser importance in the same conservation package as significant areas. However, all contracts must include sites that fulfil the BNCC. In these cases, payments for minor natural values were minimal. In addition, the latitude in price negotiations (+/- 15 per cent) was removed from the formalised NVT. One other change from the original NVT scheme is that most of the new contracts are permanent rather than for a period of ten years. The new formal policy instrument is now very different from what was successfully implemented in southwestern Finland. In other words, NVT changed as it became formalised. The EU and Finland redefined it to suit their purposes, their authorities, and their competencies. The new product differs from the original general idea. This formalisation process highlights potential institutional barriers to experimenting or learning through experiments, such as inflexible legal norms or their interpretation.
Golden eagle
The golden eagle compensation scheme has been in place since 2000. During this time, the number of known nesting territories has increased from approximately 175 in 1999 to 310-390 in 2012 (http://www.metsa.fi/sivustot/metsa/fi/Luonnonsuojelu/Lajitjaluontotyypit/Uhanalaisetelaimet/Maakotka/Sivut/Maakotka.aspx (17.05.2012). In ecological terms, the scheme can be considered a success. The scheme has also earned the approval of those involved. A survey conducted in 2005 indicated that the reindeer owners were roughly split between those who were fully or mostly satisfied (48 per cent) and those who were not (41 per cent), even though a larger share had a positive view of the scheme (
Apart from the changes made to the compensation rate, which has increased with the market price for reindeer meat, the scheme has remained almost the same over time. An amendment (amendment 839/2005) was made in 2005 to take unoccupied territories into account if decorated nests or offspring had been found in the previous two years. This amendment was based on the fact that golden eagles may have several nests in a single territory, some of which may not be known, and a pair may change its nesting site from year to year (
According to a representative of the Forest and Parks Services, co-operation between the researchers and reindeer owners has been smooth (
Having covered some key features and properties of these two PES schemes, the question of why these instruments have succeeded remains. We argue that there are three major elements to the success of these schemes. These elements are institutional entrepreneurship, trust, and crowding-in.
One citizen – Raimo Hakila – was particularly active in NVT. He had the entrepreneurial creativity that the scheme needed. This breed of entrepreneurship is institutional because it led to the renewal of the entire setting of organised and unorganised collective action (
A few common features in entrepreneurial activities help explain why they become successful. As a radical invention, NVT promised to change habits of thought and organisational routines that hindered the ability to view protection and production as coexisting, i.e., protection as a mode of production. Because of these changes in thinking and routines, the protection of forest biodiversity no longer meant that the protected areas were permanently excluded from the realm of meaningful use. Instead, as part of NVT, the protected areas came to be seen as part of the economic realm. The incentive not only motivated the forest owners and administrators to act in new ways but also motivated them to think differently, which is one aspect of successful habit change. In other words, the habits of thought (language use) changed, and the concept of Luonnonarvokauppa (natural values trading) came to denote all types of voluntary and fixed-time protection and became a metaphor that created opportunities for productive protection. A similar shift in habits occurred in Lapland. Under the new scheme, the presence of the golden eagle is an economic asset, not a nuisance that hinders economic activities. The protection of biodiversity is internalised in the practices of reindeer husbandry.
One could say that the habits of the regulator and the agents changed. The space of possible economic actions was altered, which had long-term effects on forest owners and reindeer herders and on the principals in charge of how these instruments are exercised and developed. Drawing from the legal literature, we can see that the legal equivalent of the principal – the regulator – does have the final say in terms of how the instruments are designed and implemented. The regulatees faced an NVT that was quite different after the experimental phase written into the Law of Sustainable Financing of Forestry. The habits of mind of the regulatees had, however, already changed in favour of NVT. The strong positive image of its principles was sustained even though the scheme itself was now much tighter than it was in the experimental phase. This type of institutional surprise did not occur with the golden eagle because of the scheme’s tight initial design.
Both of our cases indicate that the Schumpeterian creation of a new product, producer, seller, field, and market requires more than simply a shift in language and modes of speaking; it requires motivated action (
In modern law, the key normative function of the legal system to provide security and stability is achieved ideally through fixed norms and standards. Regulatory instruments based on voluntary action and flexible norms, such as the instruments considered in our case studies, seem to contradict these key legal values (
Trust has been defined in various ways, but a common feature of all the definitions is reciprocity (
In our cases, the legislator enabled trust to be built by choosing the use of voluntary instruments. The use of coercive rules and criminal sanctions can deprive people of the experience of being trusted, which destroys the possibility of trust. In that case, legal norms become surrogates for trust. Seen from another perspective, the regulatee must have confidence in the institutional arrangement, broadly understood, that the regulator has initiated and implemented (
What is relevant for our case studies is how the sense of being trusted affects individual behaviour and character and identifying the effects in a wider setting of collaboration. Being trusted means being held accountable for the trust of the truster, being held to a standard of behaviour that allows relationships to form and be sustained, and being held responsible by social approbation and feelings of guilt and failure (
The theory of reciprocity suggests the importance of building trust rather than relying on criminal sanctions and coercive regulations, as trust motivates people to act in certain ways (
In addition to creating conditions that enable trust to be built, trust must be sustained. As multi-round public good experiments have shown, communication and interaction are critical elements in producing and sustaining trust (
Communication is also relevant to the question of what binds a trusted person. Although potential harm to reputation and personal loss serve as motivations to maintain trust, those are not expressions of trust as such but rather calculations. According to
When selecting regulatory instruments to be used, a pragmatic legislator may sacrifice the coherence of the legal system to achieve the best societal outcome. In our case, the best outcome is biodiversity protection. For instance, financial incentive schemes such as NVT and the golden eagle compensation scheme might contradict the legal system, which prohibits the intentional destruction of biodiversity. In other words, why should society pay people to obey the law?
The use of voluntary and economic instruments has been accused of contradicting the polluter-pays principle and moral norms (
The question of whether the state has a legal duty to pay compensation for losses caused by wildlife is legally unclear and even debatable, but it is certainly reasonable to cover these losses to avoid more serious harms and conflicts. Refusal to compensate those losses would contribute to the strengthening of the emotional regime in favour of the illegal killing of damage-causing animals (
There is also a concern that economic incentives create an unsuitable attitude towards conservation: the intrinsic value of biodiversity will not be honoured, and biodiversity instead becomes a means to receive income. For instance, payments for ecosystem services have sometimes been shown to have an adverse effect by decreasing the intrinsic motivations to contribute to ecosystem services. This phenomenon, also called “crowding-out”, occurs when internal intrinsic motivations are in conflict with external (economic) incentives (
But notice that if the actual payment is not cash but, for instance a health service that is worth money the crowding-out effect does not exists to the same extent (
The purpose of this paper was to explore why NVT and the protection of the golden eagle can be considered successful biodiversity policies. We have provided a detailed description of the substantive and procedural details of these instruments. We have identified the following reasons for the success of these schemes. First, there was an institutional entrepreneur, that is, an active individual or a group who initiated the key principles of the scheme. Second, this entrepreneur created social incentives for the stakeholders to collaborate in drafting the rules, principles, and practices for the schemes, which in turn, developed agents’ confidence in the schemes and trust amongst the agents. Third, due to the collaborative changes in habits of mind and action, the schemes fit with the productive practices and customs of local livelihoods and encouraged the agents and regulatees to voluntarily adjust their behaviour.
This study also highlights the potential institutional barriers that may prevent learning through regulatory experiments and developing governance accordingly. On the one hand, regulatory flexibility and willing regulators are needed for experiments to take place. On the other hand, adaptability and reflexivity in the legal system are needed to learn from those experiments. As the NVT case clearly indicates, the strict interpretation of EU norms did not allow the scheme to be implemented in its original form, despite its success. Thus, ways to enhance the adaptive capacity (
Juha Hiedanpää would like to thank the Academy of Finland (253750) and Juha Hiedanpää and Suvi Borgström would like to thank the BIOMOT- project (FP7 grant agreement 282625) for inspiration and funding.